Method Of Equal Shares
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

The Method of Equal Shares (in early papers the method has been also referred to as Rule X, but since 2022 the authors started using the name "method of equal shares") is a proportional method of counting ballots that applies to
participatory budgeting Participatory budgeting (PB) is a type of citizen sourcing in which ordinary people decide how to allocate part of a municipal or public budget through a process of democratic deliberation and decision-making. Participatory budgeting allows ...
to committee elections and to simultaneous public decisions. It can be used, when the voters vote via
approval ballot An approval ballot, also called an unordered ballot, is a ballot in which a voter may vote for any number of candidates simultaneously, rather than for just one candidate. Candidates that are selected in a voter's ballot are said to be ''approved'' ...
s,
ranked ballots The term ranked voting (also known as preferential voting or ranked choice voting) refers to any voting system in which voters rank their candidates (or options) in a sequence of first or second (or third, etc.) on their respective ballots. Ran ...
or cardinal ballots. If each voter has equal entitlement and each voter submits approval preferences, the Method of Equal Shares is a specific rule in a more general class of rules called PB-EAR that was designed earlier in 2019 by Aziz and Lee for ordinal preferences (that include approval ballots).


Motivation

The method is an alternative to the knapsack algorithm which is used by most cities even though it is a disproportional method. For example, if 51% of the population support 10 red projects and 49% support 10 blue projects, and the money suffices only for 10 projects, the knapsack budgeting will choose the 10 red supported by the 51%, and ignore the 49% altogether. In contrast, the method of equal shares would pick 5 blue and 5 red projects. The method guarantees
proportional representation Proportional representation (PR) refers to a type of electoral system under which subgroups of an electorate are reflected proportionately in the elected body. The concept applies mainly to geographical (e.g. states, regions) and political divis ...
: it satisfies the strongest known variant of the
justified representation Justified representation (JR) is a criterion for evaluating the fairness of electoral systems in multiwinner voting, particularly in multiwinner approval voting. It can be seen as an adaptation of the proportional representation criterion to appr ...
axiom that is known to be satisfiable in participatory budgeting.


Intuitive explanation

In the context of participatory budgeting the method assumes that the municipal budget is initially evenly distributed among the voters. Each time a project is selected its cost is divided among those voters who supported the project and who still have money. The savings of these voters are decreased accordingly. If the voters vote via
approval ballot An approval ballot, also called an unordered ballot, is a ballot in which a voter may vote for any number of candidates simultaneously, rather than for just one candidate. Candidates that are selected in a voter's ballot are said to be ''approved'' ...
s, then the cost of a selected project is distributed equally among the voters; if they vote via cardinal ballots, then the cost is distributed proportionally to the utilities the voters enjoy from the project. The rule selects the projects which can be paid this way, starting with those that minimise the voters' marginal costs per utility.


Example 1

The following example with 100 voters and 9 projects illustrates how the rule works. In this example the total budget equals $1000, that is it allows to select five from the nine available projects. See the animated diagram below, which illustrates the behaviour of the rule.
File:MethodOfEqualShares-Example1.png, none,
There are 9 projects. For example, the third group of 11 voters voted for D and G. The total budget of $1000 is divided equally among 100 voters. Each voter is given 10. Click on the arrow above the image in order to see the next steps of the method.
File:MethodOfEqualShares-Example1a.png, none,
Project D obtained most votes. If we divided the cost of D equally among its supporters, each voter would pay $3.03. D is the project that minimises the maximal voter payment and so it is selected.
File:MethodOfEqualShares-Example1b.png, none,
Project A obtained 60 votes. Analogously to the previous step: if we divided the cost of A equally among its supporters, each voter would pay at most $3.33. Project A minimises the maximal voter payment and so is selected.
File:MethodOfEqualShares-Example1c.png, none,
Project C obtained 56 votes and is selected in the third round. Each supporter of C needs to pay $3.64, and this is the minimal possible payment. At this point the first 46 voters run out of their money.
File:MethodOfEqualShares-Example1d.png, none,
In the fourth step project G is selected. Some voters do not have enough money to participate equally in the purchase, so they pay all money left. The maximal payment for this candidate equals $6.97.
File:MethodOfEqualShares-Example1e.png, none,
In the last step, project H is selected. Now, only the fourth group of voters has money. They have enough money to afford the project they voted for. The maximal payment for the selected project is now $10.
The budget is first divided equally among the voters, thus each voters gets $10. Project \mathrm received most votes, and it is selected in the first round. If we divided the cost of \mathrm equally among the voters, who supported \mathrm, each of them would pay \$200/66 \approx \$3.03. In contrast, if we selected, e.g., \mathrm, then the cost per voter would be \$200/46 \approx \$4.34. The method selects first the project that minimises the price per voter. Note that in the last step project \mathrm was selected even though there were projects which were supported by more voters, say \mathrm. This is because, the money that the supporters of \mathrm had the right to control, was used previously to justify the selection of \mathrm, \mathrm, and \mathrm. On the other hand, the voters who voted for \mathrm form 20% of the population, and so shall have right to decide about 20% of the budget. Those voters supported only \mathrm, and this is why this project was selected. For a more detailed example including cardinal ballots see
Example 2 Example may refer to: * '' exempli gratia'' (e.g.), usually read out in English as "for example" * .example, reserved as a domain name that may not be installed as a top-level domain of the Internet ** example.com, example.net, example.org, e ...
.


Definition

This section presents the definition of the rule for cardinal ballots. See
discussion Conversation is interactive communication between two or more people. The development of conversational skills and etiquette is an important part of socialization. The development of conversational skills in a new language is a frequent focus ...
for a discussion on how to apply this definition to
approval ballot An approval ballot, also called an unordered ballot, is a ballot in which a voter may vote for any number of candidates simultaneously, rather than for just one candidate. Candidates that are selected in a voter's ballot are said to be ''approved'' ...
s and
ranked ballots The term ranked voting (also known as preferential voting or ranked choice voting) refers to any voting system in which voters rank their candidates (or options) in a sequence of first or second (or third, etc.) on their respective ballots. Ran ...
. We have a set of projects P = \, and a set of voters N = \. For each project p \in P let \mathrm(p) denote its cost, and let b denote the size of the available municipal budget. For each voter i \in N and each project p \in P let u_i(p) denote the i's cardinal ballot on c, that is the number that quantifies the level of appreciation of voter i towards project p. The method of equal shares works in rounds. At the beginning it puts an equal part of the budget, in each voter's virtual bank account, b_i = b/n. In each round the method selects one project according to the following procedure.


Example 2

The following diagram illustrates the behaviour of the method.
File:MethodOfEqualShares-Example2.png, none,
There are 8 available projects and 250 voters. For example, the first 65 voters assign value 30 to project B and value 10 to projects E and G. The total budget of $2500 is divided equally among 250 voters. Each voter is given $10. Click on the arrow above the image in order to see the next steps of the method.
File:MethodOfEqualShares-Example2a.png, none,
Project B is selected first, and its cost is divided proportionally to the values that the voters assigned to the project. In this case, this means it is divided equally among the voters from the first and the second group. Each such voter pays $2, and for those $2 they get the utility of 30. Thus the maximal payment-per-utility equals 2/30 \approx 0.066 . If a different project was selected, the maximal payment-per-utility would be higher.
File:MethodOfEqualShares-Example2b.png, none,
Consider project G and the payments presented in the picture. The payments are not equal, but they are still proportional to the values that the voters' assigned to G. The maximal voter's payment-per-utility for project G equals 1/10 = 4/40 = 10/100 = 0.1 and this value is minimal across all projects. Consequently, G is selected. After this round the voters from the fourth group have run out of money.
File:MethodOfEqualShares-Example2c.png, none,
In the third round project F is selected. Every supporter of F pays an equal part of the price - except for voters from the fourth group, who have no money. If they had any, they would also need to participate. Nevertheless, the maximal payment-per-utility for project F is minimal (it equals 0.2), hence F is elected.
File:MethodOfEqualShares-Example2d.png, none,
In the fourth round, project E is elected. Consider the payments presented in the picture, and note that the voters from the third group have too little money to participate in paying proportionally to their utilities, yet they all still have $4 dollars left. In such case, they pay all money they still have. The maximal payment-per-utility (paid by the voters from the first group) is minimal, and equals circa 0.54.
File:MethodOfEqualShares-Example2e.png, none,
In the last step, project C is elected. The voters from the second and the sixth group have too little money to participate in paying proportionally to their utilities, hence they pay as much as possible. The maximal payment-per-utility is paid for the fifth group of voters and equals 0.7.
File:MethodOfEqualShares-Example2e.png, none,
The rule spent $2380 out of $2500 in the budget. While the voters from the first and the fifth group have positive savings, no project can be afforded by their supporters. Hence the algorithm stops. The outcome can be further completed. According to the utilitarian strategy project H would be selected as its cost per utility equals 110 / (2\cdot 50 + 1\cdot 10 + 1 \cdot 55) and is maximal across the projects that would fit within the budget constraint.


Discussion

This section provides a discussion on other variants of the method of equal shares.


Other types of ballots

The method of equal shares can be used with other types of voters ballots.


Approval ballots

The method can be applied in two ways to the setting where the voters vote by marking the projects they like (see Example 1): # Setting u_i(p) = \mathrm(p) if project p is approved by voter i , and u_i(p) = 0 otherwise. This assumes that the utility of a voter equals the total amount of money spent on the projects supported by the voter. This assumption is commonly used in other methods of counting approval ballots for participatory budgeting, for example in the knapsack algorithm, and typically results in selecting fewer more expensive projects. # Setting u_i(p) = 1 if project p is approved by voter i , and u_i(p) = 0 otherwise. This assumes that the utility of a voter equals the number of approved selected projects. This typically results in selecting more but less expensive projects.


Ranked ballots

The method applies to the model where the voters vote by ranking the projects from the most to the least preferred one. Assuming
lexicographic preferences In economics, lexicographic preferences or lexicographic orderings describe comparative preferences where an agent prefers any amount of one good (X) to any amount of another (Y). Specifically, if offered several bundles of goods, the agent will ch ...
, one can use the convention that u_i(p) depends on the position of project p in the voter's i ranking, and that u_i(p)/u_i(p') \to \infty , whenever i ranks p as more preferred than p' . Formally, the method is defined as follows. For each voter i \in N let \succ_i denote the ranking of voter i over the projects. For example, Y \succ_i X \succ_i Z means that Y is the most preferred project from the perspective of voter i, X is the voter's second most preferred project and Z is the least preferred project. In this example we say that project Y is ranked in the first position and write \mathrm_i(Y) = 1, project X is ranked in the second position (\mathrm_i(X) = 2), and Z in the third position (\mathrm_i(Z) = 3). Each voter is initially assigned an equal part of the budget b_i = b/n. The rule proceeds in rounds, in each round:


Committee elections

In the context of committee elections the projects are typically called candidates. It is assumed that cost of each candidate equals one; then, the budget b can be interpreted as the number of candidates in the committee that should be selected.


Unspent budget

The method of equal shares can return a set of projects that does not exhaust the whole budget. There are multiple ways to use the unspent budget:


Properties

In the context of committee elections the method is often compared to Proportional Approval Voting (PAV), since both methods are proportional (they satisfy the axiom of Extended Justified Representation (EJR)). The difference between the two methods can be described as follow. MES is similar to the Phragmen's sequential rule. The difference is that in MES the voters are given their budgets upfront, while in the Phragmen's sequential rule the voters earn money continuously over time. The methods compare as follows: MES with adjusting initial budget, PAV and Phragmen's voting rules can all be viewed as extensions of the
D'Hondt method The D'Hondt method, also called the Jefferson method or the greatest divisors method, is a method for allocating seats in parliaments among federal states, or in party-list proportional representation systems. It belongs to the class of highest ...
to the setting where the voters can vote for individual candidates rather than for political parties. MES further extends to
participatory budgeting Participatory budgeting (PB) is a type of citizen sourcing in which ordinary people decide how to allocate part of a municipal or public budget through a process of democratic deliberation and decision-making. Participatory budgeting allows ...
.


Implementation

Below there is a Python implementation of the method that applies to participatory budgeting. For the model of committee elections, the rules is implemented as a part of the Python packag
''abcvoting''
import math def leq(a, b): return a < b or math.isclose(a, b) # N: a list of voters. # C: a list of projects (candidates). # cost: a dictionary that assigns each project its cost. # b: the total available budget. # u: a dictionary; u i] is the value that voter i assigns to candidate c. # an empty entry means that the corresponding value u i] equals 0. def complete_utilitarian(N, C, cost, u, b, W): util = committee_cost = sum( ost[cfor_c_in_W.html" ;"title=".html" ;"title="ost[c">ost[cfor c in W">.html" ;"title="ost[c">ost[cfor c in W while True: next_candidate = None highest_util = float("-inf") for c in C.difference(W): if leq(committee_cost + cost b): if util[c] / cost[c] > highest_util: next_candidate = c highest_util = util[c] / cost[c] if next_candidate is None: break W.add(next_candidate) committee_cost += cost ext_candidate return W def method_of_equal_shares(N, C, cost, u, b): W = set() total_utility = supporters = budget = while True: next_candidate = None lowest_rho = float("inf") for c in C.difference(W): if leq(cost sum( udget[ifor_i_in_supporters[c.html" ;"title=".html" ;"title="udget[i">udget[ifor i in supporters[c">.html" ;"title="udget[i">udget[ifor i in supporters[c)): supporters_sorted = sorted(supporters key=lambda i: budget / u i]) price = cost[c] util = total_utility[c] for i in supporters_sorted: if leq(price * u i], budget * util): break price -= budget util -= u i] rho = price / util \ if not math.isclose(util, 0) and not math.isclose(price, 0) \ else budget upporters_sorted[-1_/_u_supporters_sorted[-1.html" ;"title="1.html" ;"title="upporters_sorted[-1">upporters_sorted[-1 / u supporters_sorted[-1">1.html" ;"title="upporters_sorted[-1">upporters_sorted[-1 / u supporters_sorted[-1 if rho < lowest_rho: next_candidate = c lowest_rho = rho if next_candidate is None: break W.add(next_candidate) for i in N: budget -= min(budget[i], lowest_rho * u[next_candidate][i]) return complete_utilitarian(N, C, cost, u, b, W) # one of the possible completions


References

{{voting systems Vote counting Multi-winner electoral systems Preferential electoral systems Proportional representation electoral systems Participatory budgeting Cardinal electoral systems Approval voting